Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-7qhmt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-29T01:31:06.924Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

John Stuart Mill and Concepts of Nature

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 April 2010

Margaret Schabas
Affiliation:
York University

Extract

Why did Mill draw such a firm line between nature and society, and what did he mean by the claim that only permanent or necessary truths could be gleaned in nature? Why are the laws of production able to transcend the social realm and thereby attain a higher epistemological standing? Was Mill the first (and possibly the last) to make this distinction, or does it conform with a long tradition within the history of economic thought?

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Philosophical Association 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Berg, Maxine 1980 The Machinery Question and the Making of Political Economy, 1815–1848. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark 1978 Economic Theory in Retrospect. 3rd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cartwright, Nancy 1983 How the Laws of Physics Lie. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, Avi J. 1989Prices, Capital, and the One-Commodity Model of Neoclassical and Classical Theories.” History of Political Economy, 21, 1:231–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cropsey, Joseph 1975 “Adam Smith and Political Philosophy.” In Essays on Adam Smith. Edited by Skinner, Andrew and Wilson, Thomas. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Neil B. 1972Mill and Cairnes and the Emergence of Marginalism in England.” History of Political Economy, 4 (Fall): 344–63.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Neil B. 1974The Success of Mill's Principles.” History of Political Economy, 6 (Spring): 119–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Marchi, Neil B. 1986Mill's Unrevised Philosophy of Economics: A Comment on Hausman.” Philosophy of Science, 53: 89100.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, , Ysidro, Francis 1967 Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences. 1881. Rpt. New York: Augustus M. Kelly.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel 1981John Stuart Mill's Philosophy of Economics.” Philosophy of Science, 48: 383–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edgeworth, Francis Ysidro 1992 The Inexact and Separate Science of Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hollander, Samuel 1983William Whewell and John Stuart Mill on the Methodology of Political Economy.” Studies in the History and Philosophy of Science, 4, 2: 127–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollander, Samuel 1985 The Economics of John Stuart Mill. 2 vols. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Istvan, Hunt, and , Michael Ignatieff, eds. 1983 Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hutchison, Terence Wilmot 1988 Before Adam Smith: The Emergence of Political Economy, 1662-1776. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Ingrao, Bruna, and Giorgio, Israel 1990 The Invisible Hand: Economic Equilibrium in the History of Science. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Jevons, William Stanley 1890 “Utilitarianism.” In Pure Logic and Other Minor Works. Edited by Adamson, Robert and Jevons, Harriet A.. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Jevons, William Stanley 1905 The Principles of Economics and Other Papers. Edited by Higgs, Henry. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Jevons, William Stanley 1965 The Theory of Political Economy. 5th ed. 1957. Rpt. New York: Augustus M. Kelly.Google Scholar
Leary, David E. 1983The Fate and Influence of John Stuart Mill's Proposed Science of Ethology.” Journal of the History of Ideas, 43: 153–62.Google Scholar
Maloney, John 1985 Marshall, Orthodoxy, and the Professionalisation of Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred 1920 The Principles of Economics. 8th ed. London: Macmillan. Meek.Google Scholar
Ronald, 1962 The Economics of Physiocracy. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart 1965 Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, 1871 (7th ed.), Vols. 2-3, Principles of Political Economy. Edited by Robson, John M.. Rpt. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart 1967 "Essays on Some Unsettled Questions of Political Economy." In Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, 1844, Vol. 4, Essays on Economics and Society. Edited by John M. Robson. Rpt. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mill, , Stuart, John 1969 "On Nature." In Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, 1974, Vol. 10, Essays on Ethics, Religion, and Society. Edited by Robson, John M.. Rpt. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mill, , Stuart, John 1973 Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, 1872 (8th ed.), Vols. 7-8, A System of Logic: Ratiocinative and Inductive. Edited by Robson, John M.. Rpt. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip 1989 More Heat than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noller, C. W. 1972Jevons on Cost.” Southern Economic Journal, 39 (July): 113–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robson, John M. 1976 “Rational Animals and Others.” In James and John Stuart Mill: Papers of the Centenary Conference. Edited by Robson, John M. and Laine, Michael. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotwein, Eugene, ed. 1955 David Hume: Writings on Economics. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Ryan, Alan 1974 J. S. Mill. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Ryan, Alan 1990 The Philosophy of John Stuart Mill. 2nd ed. Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities Press International.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren 1966 The Classical Theory of Economic Policy. New York: World.Google Scholar
Schabas, Margaret 1990 A World Ruled by Number: William Stanley Jevons and the Rise of Mathematical Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneewind, J. B., ed. 1970 Mill. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954 A History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schwartz, Pedro 1973 The New Political Economy of J. S. Mill. London: Weidenfeld and Nicholson.Google Scholar
Schweber, S. S. 1985 “The Wider British Context in Darwin's Theorizing.” In The Darwinian Heritage. Edited by Kohn, David. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Vardaman R. 1985John Stuart Mill's Famous Distinction between Production and Distribution.” Economics and Philosophy, 1 (October): 267–84.Google Scholar
Whitaker, John K. 1975J. S. Mill's Methodology.” Journal of Political Economy, 83 (October): 1033–50.Google Scholar
Wise, M. Norton 1989Work and Waste: Political Economy and Natural Philosophy in Nineteenth-Century Britain.” Parts 1 and 2. History of Science, 27:263301; 27:391-449.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wise, M. Norton 1990Work and Waste: Political Economy and Natural Philosophy in Nineteenth-Century Britain.” Part 3. History of Science, 28:221–61.Google Scholar
Young, Robert 1985 Darwin's Metaphor: Nature's Place in Victorian Culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar